Opinion Deep Dives Regulatory

Cracking Down on Orphan Drug Abuse: The ORPHAN Cures Act and Its Impact

orphan drug price protest

Orphan Drug Profits vs. Patients: The Orphan Drug Act of 1983 was meant to encourage treatments for rare diseases, but critics say it’s now being exploited for profit. Lawmakers across party lines have decried how pharma “misuse[s] the Orphan Drug Act” to secure monopolies and egregious prices. Senator Bernie Sanders blasted one company’s $375,000 orphan drug price as “a blatant fleecing of American taxpayers” and “an immoral exploitation of patients… Simply put, it is corporate greed” (2019). Such abuses have spurred Congress to act. In late 2023, a bipartisan group introduced the Optimizing Research Progress Hope And New Cures Act (ORPHAN Cures Act) to rein in orphan drug loopholes and refocus on patients’ needs.

Senators Sound the Alarm on Orphan Drug “Loopholes”

Prominent U.S. senators from both parties have openly criticized how drugmakers game the orphan drug system. In February 2020, Sen. Bill Cassidy (R-LA) warned that pharma “monopolies…drive drug prices up, making drugs unaffordable,” vowing that “drug companies must have the means to innovate, but they should not be allowed to exploit the market”. Likewise, Sen. Jeanne Shaheen (D-NH) urged Congress to “crack down on drug manufacturers who abuse the system” to block affordable competition. Even earlier, a trio of Republican senators in 2017 pushed the GAO to investigate “potential abuses” of orphan law amid reports of five- and six-figure annual prices for orphan drugs. The outrage spans the aisle: drugmakers “misusing” orphan status for profit is squarely in lawmakers’ sights. As one pharmacy benefits executive put it, “This is an example of how some companies misuse the Orphan Drug Act…we have been vocal in our support of amending this legislation to prevent such situations”. These concerns set the stage for the ORPHAN Cures Act as a legislative fix.

What the ORPHAN Cures Act Would Change

The ORPHAN Cures Act aims to close loopholes and reset incentives in the orphan drug system. Introduced in late 2023 and reintroduced in Feb 2025, this bill targets how orphan drugs are treated under the new Medicare price negotiation program. Currently, the 2022 Inflation Reduction Act (IRA) exempts a drug from Medicare price negotiations only if it’s approved for a single rare disease use – an incentive for companies to keep indications narrow. The ORPHAN Cures Act would expand the definition of “orphan drug” under the IRA, so that drugs with more than one orphan indication (and no non-orphan uses) also stay exempt from price controls. In other words, a rare disease therapy could treat multiple rare conditions without triggering Medicare’s pricing power. The bill also tweaks the timeline: it would exclude any period during which a drug had orphan designation from counting toward Medicare’s negotiation clock. Practically, this delays when a drug becomes eligible for government price-setting if it later gains a non-orphan use. For example, if a drug spent 7 years as orphan-only, those years wouldn’t count toward the IRA’s 9–13 year post-approval window for negotiations. Together, these changes extend market protection for orphan drugs, encouraging companies to pursue additional rare disease indications without fear of losing revenue to Medicare cuts.

Beyond the IRA tweaks, policymakers backing the Act have a broader goal to curb orphan designation abuses. They are targeting the “salami slicing” of diseases into ultra-niche subtypes to snag multiple orphan exclusivities. In recent years some firms sought separate orphan approvals for what are essentially variations of the same disease – a tactic regulators and experts say “must be opposed effectively”. The ORPHAN Cures debate also spotlighted the 7-year orphan exclusivity period granted by the 1983 law. Under current rules, even a widely used drug can get seven years of market exclusivity by claiming it wouldn’t be profitable without it – and then rake in windfall profits once approved. That exclusivity remains even if the drug becomes very profitable, blocking competitors. Lawmakers like Sen. Tammy Baldwin have condemned this as a loophole that lets companies “keep competition off the market and rake in profits” unfairly. While the ORPHAN Cures Act primarily focuses on the IRA’s provisions, it aligns with parallel bipartisan efforts to tighten the Orphan Drug Act’s criteria of rarity and economic need. Its spirit is to ensure true rare disease drugs get support, while preventing firms from “exploiting the market” via orphan status technicalities.

In short, the ORPHAN Cures Act rebalances the incentives: it promises rare disease innovators that multiple orphan cures won’t be punished by price controls, but it also puts industry on notice that games like indication-splitting and perpetual exclusivity will no longer be tolerated. As BIO’s CEO summed up, the bill “revers[es] IRA’s perverse incentives” against rare disease research – but patient advocates counter that it also risks cementing orphan drug monopolies. This tension has huge stakes for drug companies and patients alike.

Blockbuster Orphan Drugs – And Who Stands to Lose Millions

Some of biotech’s most lucrative products are orphan drugs, and reforms could hit their bottom lines. Industry giants like Vertex, Alexion, and Biogen have grown rich on therapies for rare diseases – and could see profit margins squeezed if orphan exclusivity or pricing rules are tightened.

  • Vertex Pharmaceuticals built a cystic fibrosis empire on orphan drugs. CF affects only ~30,000 Americans, yet Vertex’s patented CF modulator drugs (like Trikafta, Symdeko, Orkambi, Kalydeco) are priced around $311,000 per patient per year in the U.S. (2018 figure) and have virtually no competition. As a result, Vertex’s CF franchise earned $10.9 billion in 2024 alone – astonishing revenue for a rare disease portfolio. Vertex has aggressively defended its high prices overseas; it famously refused a £500 million NHS offer (≈$660 M) to provide Orkambi, insisting on a higher price. For years, UK patients were denied the drug due to this standoff. Such price-gouging under orphan protection fueled Vertex’s profits but tarnished its reputation. If U.S. law changes to curb orphan exclusivity or allow Medicare to negotiate CF drug prices, Vertex could be forced to cut prices – shrinking its multi-billion-dollar CF cash cow.
  • Alexion Pharmaceuticals (now part of AstraZeneca) is another case. Its flagship drug Soliris (eculizumab) treats ultra-rare blood and immune disorders and is one of the world’s most expensive medicines, with an annual price tag around $500,000 per patient. Thanks to orphan exclusivity and multiple rare indications (paroxysmal nocturnal hemoglobinuria, atypical HUS, myasthenia gravis, etc.), Soliris monopolized its niches and reaped $4.1 billion in sales in 2020. Alexion leveraged that orphan-fueled revenue to develop follow-up drugs like Ultomiris – and was acquired by AstraZeneca for $39 billion in 2021. If reforms prevent “indication stacking” (Soliris had four orphan indications approved) or bring competition sooner, Alexion/AZ could lose years of high-priced monopoly sales. Indeed, biosimilars are on the horizon: Amgen will launch a Soliris biosimilar in 2025 as Alexion’s protections expire. Analysts have long warned that Alexion’s rare disease franchise profits would erode once rivals enter. The ORPHAN Cures Act, by keeping multi-orphan drugs free from Medicare price cuts, actually shields Alexion’s model – but other proposed orphan reforms (like trimming exclusivity if sales boom) would directly threaten its half-million-per-patient revenue stream.
  • Biogen also rode an orphan drug to blockbuster status with Spinraza (nusinersen) for spinal muscular atrophy. Spinraza debuted in 2016 at an eye-popping $750,000 for the first year of treatment, then $375,000 annually thereafter. This was unprecedented for a pediatric rare disease drug, sparking outrage and comparisons to Gilead’s notorious $84k Hepatitis C drug. Biogen nonetheless made billions: Spinraza’s sales hit $1.7 billion in 2018 and peaked around $2 billion/year before competition arrived. By 2024, it still generated about $1.6 billion annually despite newer therapies for SMA. Spinraza’s orphan exclusivity (2017–2024) kept generics off the market, and its high price extracted huge sums from health systems. If future orphan drugs face earlier price negotiation or shorter exclusivity, companies like Biogen could lose the ability to sustain such sky-high pricing for years on end. Wall Street took note when Biogen’s “$375K per year” pricing drew backlash – analysts warned it could become “the straw that breaks the camel’s back” on rare drug pricing tolerance. In an environment of reform, investors fear the kind of free rein Biogen enjoyed with Spinraza may not be possible for the next rare disease therapy.

Beyond these examples, many Big Pharma players have profitable orphan drugs that could be affected. Johnson & Johnson’s Darzalex (for myeloma), Bristol Myers’ Revlimid (for multiple myeloma & MDS), and Roche’s Hemlibra (for hemophilia) all started as orphan-designated therapies and now reap billions in revenue. Any policy that tightens orphan criteria or lowers protected pricing could dent the future earnings of these “blockbuster orphans.” Small wonder, then, that the industry is pushing hard to influence the outcome.

Industry Lobbying vs. Patient Advocates: Battle over Reform

The pharmaceutical industry has mobilized aggressively to shape the orphan drug reform debate – while patient advocates and payers are pushing back. On one side, biotech companies and trade groups are lobbying to preserve the lucrative orphan status quo. BioPharma executives argue that maintaining strong incentives is essential for rare disease innovation. In fact, more than two dozen biotech CEOs signed a public letter urging Congress to pass the ORPHAN Cures Act, portraying it as critical to “removing a disincentive” in the IRA and spurring investment in rare cures. Organizations like the Rare Disease Company Coalition and the Save Rare Treatments Task Force (an alliance of patient and industry groups) have strongly backed the bill, warning that the IRA’s current rules “impede rare disease innovation and investment”. BIO (Biotechnology Innovation Org) likewise calls the Act a “welcome…bipartisan fix” needed to continue “40 years of progress” under the Orphan Drug Act. In short, the industry’s message is that now is not the time to weaken orphan drug incentives – and it has poured lobbying resources into that message.

At the same time, pharma is deploying stealth tactics at the state level to guard orphan profits. As multiple states set up Prescription Drug Affordability Boards to cap excessive drug costs, drugmakers have been pushing laws to exempt orphan drugs from these price limits. In March 2024, reporting showed industry lobbyists persuading state lawmakers that any cost controls on orphan medicines would “cause companies to halt sales or stop R&D for rare diseases”. Consumer advocates argue these blanket exemptions are simply aimed at preserving profits for many drugs that, despite an orphan label, are big sellers for common conditions. They warn that pharma’s maneuvers would “increase the risk that countless patients have trouble paying for medicines” by shielding high prices from state oversight. This state-by-state lobbying reveals the industry’s broader strategy: if federal reform looms, carve out protections wherever possible to maintain orphan drug pricing power.

On the other side of the fight, patient advocacy groups and cost watchdogs argue that reforms are urgently needed to stop abuse. They contend the ORPHAN Cures Act itself is a pharma-driven ploy to lock in monopolies. In a March 2025 letter, the group Patients For Affordable Drugs Now blasted ORPHAN Cures, saying it would “undermine Medicare negotiation …allow drug companies to extend monopolies and drive up prices for patients – including for those with rare diseases like myself”. The patient group’s president, David Mitchell (a cancer patient), noted that under IRA true orphan drugs are already unlikely to be selected for negotiation (because their sales are usually below Medicare’s top expenditures). Thus, he argues, expanding the exemption is unnecessary for innovation but very useful for padding profits. Mitchell writes that ORPHAN Cures would let manufacturers “prolong their monopolies and inflate prices indefinitely” on drugs that do add new uses – even though those additional indications mean higher revenue that more than covers R&D costs. Patient coalitions and some health economists therefore oppose the bill, calling instead for stricter oversight of orphan designations and an end to “evergreening” schemes that delay competition. They point out that all the original Orphan Act incentives (7-year exclusivity, tax credits, FDA fee waivers) remain intact – so industry claims of innovation collapse are overblown. In their view, pharma’s dire warnings are a classic fear tactic to protect windfall profits at the expense of patients and taxpayers.

This clash of narratives – innovation vs. affordability – makes orphan drug reform one of the most contentious health policy battles today. Lawmakers are effectively caught between biotech lobbyists (wielding the hope of cures for thousands of untreated diseases) and patient advocates (demanding an end to exploitative pricing and “gaming” of a well-intentioned law). The outcome of this fight will determine whether the orphan drug system is steered back toward its original mission or remains, as critics say, “a system… being manipulated by drugmakers to maximize profits”.

When Orphan Status Hurts Patients: Pricey Drugs Out of Reach

Real-world examples abound of how orphan drug “incentives” can hurt patients by putting treatments out of reach. The combination of monopoly protection and sky-high prices often means that having a therapy approved is not the same as patients actually getting it. Here are a few stark cases that have fueled public anger:

  • Catalyst Pharma’s LEMS drug: For decades, patients with the rare neuromuscular disorder LEMS could get an old drug, 3,4-DAP, for free via compassionate use. Catalyst Pharmaceutical secured orphan approval for the drug (branded Firdapse) in late 2018 – and promptly set a list price of $375,000 per year. Overnight, a once-free, life-improving medicine became exorbitantly expensive. Patients and neurologists were outraged; many insurers initially refused to pay, and some patients considered going without treatment. Sen. Sanders wrote to Catalyst that this price “is…immoral… Simply put, it is corporate greed,” highlighting how the orphan monopoly enabled Catalyst to **“fleece” patients and taxpayers with impunity. An official at Express Scripts (a major pharmacy benefits manager) noted “this medication takes advantage of vulnerable patients… This is an example of how some companies misuse the Orphan Drug Act,” calling for reforms. In this case, orphan exclusivity even blocked competition: when a small family-run company tried to market a cheaper similar drug for LEMS in pediatric patients, Catalyst used its exclusivity to sue the FDA and keep the rival off the market. Patients were effectively hostage to one company’s monopoly. Only after intense pressure did Catalyst start an access program – a pattern where outrage, not normal market forces, forced a modicum of relief. The Firdapse saga became a prime exhibit in why orphan drug policy needs fixing.
  • Vertex’s CF drugs: Cystic fibrosis patients and families have repeatedly faced heartbreak as life-changing drugs remained out of reach due to price. Vertex’s CF modulators (like Orkambi and Trikafta) can dramatically improve lung function and survival. But when Vertex launched Orkambi, it set the price at roughly £105,000 per patient per year in Britain (over $130,000) – a level the UK’s NHS deemed unaffordable. For nearly three years (2016–2019), Vertex refused to lower the price, even as 200+ British CF patients died waiting for access. Patients’ families resorted to public protests and social media campaigns (“#OrkambiNow”) to shame the company. The impasse only broke after UK authorities threatened to sidestep Vertex’s patent. Similarly, in many countries Vertex’s drugs have been rationed to only the sickest patients, or delayed for years in pricing negotiations. In the U.S., insurers initially placed heavy restrictions on Orkambi and later Trikafta, given annual costs above $300k per patient. Doctors struggled with phone-book sized paperwork to get coverage approvals. Some children’s families, facing high co-pays, resorted to charity fundraisers. The orphan drug monopoly – no generics, no alternatives – meant Vertex held all the power. “Vertex is asking £105k…which the NHS insists is not value for money,” reported one investigative piece, noting the CEO’s $18 million pay was enough to treat 137 CF patients for a year. Patient advocates have cited this as evidence that “Big Pharma puts profits over lives” when it comes to rare disease treatments.
  • Biogen’s Spinraza: The $750,000 first-year price of the SMA therapy Spinraza immediately raised barriers for families. Though approved in the U.S. in 2016, it took until mid-2018 for many state Medicaid programs to cover it – and even then, with strict criteria. Oklahoma’s Medicaid, for instance, barred coverage for patients on ventilators (typically older SMA Type I children), effectively denying the drug to the most severely ill kids. Other states required periodic proof of improvement to continue coverage, knowing that stopping the drug could be life-threatening. Appeals and denials became common. A 2017 NPR/KHN report profiled a mother in Oklahoma who, after two coverage rejections, was desperate as her 4-year-old son’s motor function declined each week without Spinraza. “The longer we wait, the more [ability] will be gone,” she said, fearing permanent loss of function. Families fortunate enough to get Spinraza through insurance still faced thousands in out-of-pocket costs annually. Biogen did set up patient assistance, but only after public criticism. The stress on families and physicians to somehow obtain the $125,000-per-injection drug was immense. Dr. Jerry Avorn of Harvard Medical School summarized the absurdity: “a drug that works…that’s the good news. But how in the world did the price of $750,000 get chosen?” He likened Biogen’s pricing logic (pegging to other ultra-high orphan drug prices) to an “inflationary cycle” of wrongdoing – “If it’s wrong, it’s wrong”. In the end, Spinraza’s orphan-fueled profits flowed to Biogen, while many SMA patients had to fight or wait for access – a dynamic all too common with high-price orphan therapies.

These cases illustrate a cruel irony: a drug can win orphan approval – and accolades – yet remain financially out of reach for many who need it. The monopoly and exclusivity that come with orphan status often translate into no competition and astronomical prices, which in turn lead payers to restrict coverage or patients to forego treatment. Patient advocacy groups regularly document stories of Americans rationing doses, moving to different states for coverage, or crowdfunding to pay for orphan drugs. Physicians for rare diseases have testified to Congress that approval doesn’t equal access when a drug is priced in the stratosphere. This patient harm is a driving force behind calls to overhaul orphan drug policy. As the head of one advocacy group put it, “Drugs don’t work if people can’t afford them.”

The pharma data you wish you had. Now you do.
The pharma data you wish you had. Now you do. API-FDF Intelligence.

New Schemes: How Pharma May Adapt to Keep Profits

Pharma companies are nothing if not creative in evading regulations, and many observers predict they will develop new workarounds to preserve orphan drug windfalls if the rules change. Every time a loophole is closed, another often opens – and the stakes of orphan drug sales are so high (an estimated $185 billion in global orphan drug revenue in 2024) that firms will aggressively protect that gold mine. Here are some tactics in play or on the horizon:

  • “Partial Orphan” Labeling: One strategy has been to seek orphan designation for a drug’s initial niche use, then later expand the market to common diseases – capturing incentives without limiting revenue. A new study in Health Affairs found that for 15 top-selling drugs with both rare and common indications, fully 70% of their revenue came from treating the common conditions, not the rare ones. For example, the cancer drug Neulasta had orphan status for a rare use, yet <1% of its sales were for that use. Drugmakers can leverage orphan benefits (tax credits, fee waivers, faster reviews) to get a drug approved for a small population, then market it broadly for more prevalent diseases. This “bait-and-switch” undermines the spirit of orphan incentives, and regulators may tighten rules on it – but companies will still attempt it. We may see more drugs launched in genetically-defined “rare” subsets of common diseases, securing orphan perks, and then quickly moving into bigger patient groups. If reforms try to claw back incentives once a drug becomes a bestseller, companies might respond by splitting off separate brand names or dosing regimens for the rare vs. common indications to technically retain orphan status for one version. In essence, pharma could create artificial product distinctions to keep the orphan money flowing.
  • Evergreening & Patent Thickets: Even if indication-based exclusivity games are curbed, drugmakers will lean harder on patents and follow-on products to extend monopolies. Many orphan drugs already come to market with robust patent protection; companies can then file additional patents on manufacturing processes, formulations, or new dosing – building a “patent thicket” that deters generic challengers beyond the 7-year orphan term. For instance, Alexion shifted most patients from Soliris to Ultomiris, a tweaked longer-acting antibody, just as Soliris’s exclusivity neared its end. This kind of product hopping lets a firm restart the clock on monopoly pricing under the guise of innovation. If legislation bans “splitting indications,” companies may instead pursue “serial innovation” – slightly modifying a drug to get a new orphan approval when the old one lapses. Prior to 2017, firms could get a second 7-year exclusivity for the same drug in the same disease if they tweaked the formulation and proved some benefit. Congress closed parts of that loophole (after one notorious opioid-treatment drug tried to claim orphan exclusivity repeatedly). But manufacturers will undoubtedly look for other wrinkles, like combination therapies (pairing the orphan drug with another agent to get a new patent/exclusivity) or isomer/isotope switches, to effectively extend their monopoly beyond what reforms intend. In short, if the front door to indefinite exclusivity is locked, expect pharma to try the back door.
  • Maximizing Early Profit: Another adaptation will be front-loading drug prices and revenues in anticipation of a shorter exclusive period. If companies know a drug might face Medicare price negotiation after, say, 9 years (for small-molecule drugs) or if orphan exclusivity might be lost sooner, they have an incentive to launch at an even higher price and increase it faster to make as much money as possible before the hammer falls. We saw a glimpse of this after the IRA passed in 2022: pharma began raising prices more aggressively on drugs they expect will hit the negotiation list, essentially “get it while you can” pricing. With orphan drugs, companies could also curtail patient assistance programs or free drug programs if they know the window for profits is tighter – a move that would harm patients but preserve revenue. Moreover, some firms might strategically avoid developing certain new indications altogether under a reform regime. For example, if adding a non-orphan use would subject a drug to negotiation, a company might simply choose not to pursue that broader indication (even if it could help patients) to preserve its pricing power in the orphan realm. This is exactly the perverse incentive the ORPHAN Cures Act authors warned about: companies “disincentivized…to test whether existing [orphan] treatments also benefit other diseases” under the IRA’s current setup. While ORPHAN Cures seeks to remove that disincentive, if it doesn’t pass and IRA stays as is, we might see pharma deliberately leaving potential cures on the shelf to protect their pricier rare-disease turf – a troubling consequence of profit-driven decision-making.
  • Legislative End-Runs: Pharma will likely continue investing in lobbying as a “plan B” to any new rules. We’ve already seen the industry champion the EPIC Act (to extend IRA exemptions for small molecules from 9 to 13 years, matching biologics) and the MINI Act (to exempt gene therapies for longer). If orphan reforms pass, expect a slew of “tweaks” attached to larger bills – perhaps restoring some benefits via opaque provisions or delaying implementation. At the state level, companies may push for more preemptive laws to block states from regulating orphan drug prices (citing federal supremacy of orphan designations). The industry’s goal will be to carve out safe harbors wherever possible: if they lose a bit federally, secure it locally; if one incentive is cut, gain another tax break in exchange. This cat-and-mouse game could continue for years, as orphan drugs are simply too profitable for companies to surrender without exploiting every angle.

In sum, pharma’s likely response to tougher orphan rules is adaptation, not retreat. As one health policy expert wryly noted, “Drug companies are exceedingly good at finding the next loophole.” Policymakers will have to remain vigilant post-reform, or risk new forms of abuse emerging. The hope is that shining a light on these practices – pay-for-delay, indication slicing, patent gaming – will itself deter the worst behavior. But history suggests profit motives find a way, unless regulations are airtight and enforcement stiff. The rare disease community and regulators will need to keep asking: what are companies doing now to get around the rules? and plug the leaks as they appear.

Market Shake-Up: Who Wins if Orphan Reform Succeeds?

Should meaningful orphan drug reforms take hold – whether through the ORPHAN Cures Act’s passage or other measures – there will be winners and losers in the healthcare market. While some pharma companies may see their margins clipped, other players stand to benefit (and patients ultimately should, too):

  • Generic and Biosimilar Manufacturers: Perhaps the biggest “winners” from reducing orphan exclusivity abuse are companies that make generic drugs and biosimilars. These firms have often been locked out of rare disease markets because of extended exclusivities and patent thickets. If reforms shorten the monopoly period or stop companies from endlessly extending it, generics can enter sooner with far cheaper versions. Case in point: Soliris (eculizumab) will finally face biosimilar competition by 2025, opening a multi-billion-dollar market to generic players. Amgen, for example, has a biosimilar Soliris ready to launch – a direct result of Alexion’s orphan exclusivity lapsing. A single biosimilar entry can slash prices by 20–40%, saving payers hundreds of millions and allowing the biosimilar maker to capture new revenue. If more orphan blockbusters lose their shield a bit sooner, generic firms like Teva, Sandoz or Viatris and biosimilar specialists like Amgen, Samsung Bioepis, etc., could see major new opportunities. These companies are quietly cheering for reforms that would trigger a wave of generic entry into the rare disease space that has until now been off-limits.
  • Drug Repurposers and Startups: A reformed system could level the playing field for smaller innovators and startups. Today, a big pharma can secure orphan designation on an existing molecule and crowd out competitors even if the drug itself isn’t novel. In a world with stricter rules, smaller biotech firms that specialize in repurposing older drugs for rare diseases (via the 505(b)(2) FDA pathway) might have an easier time bringing products to market. For instance, if a “big pharma orphan” drug is no longer guaranteed 7 years of exclusivity for each tiny indication, a startup might attempt to develop a better or cheaper therapy for that same rare disease and actually have a chance to compete sooner. We could see more investment in alternative treatments for rare diseases where one company currently dominates. Additionally, startups focusing on gene therapies or curative treatments for rare diseases might gain, especially if payers and investors shift attention toward one-time cures rather than expensive chronic orphan drugs. Interestingly, some analysts suggest that if huge orphan drug profits are tempered, large companies might spin off or divest their rare disease units, which could be acquired by investment firms or startups willing to run a leaner operation. In that scenario, niche companies could profit by commercializing orphan drugs at lower prices but still sustainably (a model somewhat like in Europe with smaller commercial entities for ultra-rare drugs).
  • Payers and Healthcare Systems: While not “market players” in the profit sense, public and private payers stand to save significantly from orphan reforms – which frees up resources that can be redirected elsewhere. A recent analysis in JAMA estimated that keeping the sole-orphan drug exemption in Medicare’s negotiation (as is) would cost U.S. taxpayers billions per year in higher drug spending. Conversely, closing that exemption – i.e. negotiating orphan drug prices when appropriate – could save billions that Medicare could use to cover other therapies or benefits. State Medicaid programs, which have been brutalized by the costs of ultra-expensive orphan meds, would likewise get relief if prices come down or if cheaper competitors emerge sooner. Even private insurers could lower premiums if rare drug costs diminish. In a market sense, this might not be “profit,” but it’s a win for the broader economy. Hospital systems might also benefit, since some orphan drugs (especially enzyme replacements or gene therapies) are administered in hospitals – if those prices drop, hospitals can afford to treat more patients or reduce charges. Employers and consumers ultimately could see financial benefits; money not spent on a $300k per year drug could be wage increases or lower insurance copays instead. These diffuse “winners” don’t show up on a stock ticker, but they are central to why reform is being pursued in the first place.
  • Emerging Competitors with New Models: Finally, if the era of endless orphan monopolies wanes, we may see new business models thrive. For example, companies that specialize in “nonprofit drug development” or low-cost development could step in. There are initiatives where organizations develop and distribute certain orphan drugs at cost – today these struggle to compete with for-profit pharmas holding exclusivities. Reform could open cracks for such models to expand, which, while not profit-seeking, could “earn” in the sense of sustainability and philanthropic funding. On the flip side, big pharma might pivot more to common diseases if rare disease profit isn’t as sky-high, which opens the rare space for smaller agile firms. Investors are already evaluating these possibilities: some Wall Street analysts believe curbing orphan exclusivity could redirect venture capital toward platform technologies (like gene editing or mRNA) that can target many rare diseases efficiently, rather than pouring money into the 50th iteration of a me-too orphan drug. In essence, innovation might shift from an emphasis on “how do we maximize this one orphan drug’s price” to “how do we cheaply develop many cures and get them to patients” – a potentially more sustainable and ethical proposition.

In the near term, a clear beneficiary of reform would be any company poised to compete with a high-price orphan drug. For instance, Apellis Pharmaceuticals, which developed Empaveli (pegcetacoplan) as an alternative to Alexion’s Soliris for blood disorders, could capture market share if hospitals and payers push to replace $500k infusions with a (modestly) cheaper option. Similarly, generic drug makers for Huntington’s or ALS drugs (where orphan exclusivity delays competition) could finally come to market. Investors are taking note: when Congress talks reform, stock prices of orphan-heavy companies sometimes dip, while those of generic manufacturers tick up in anticipation.

Ultimately, the biggest “winner” of orphan drug reform, if done right, will be patients and the healthcare system. The goal is not to punish innovation, but to strip away the abusive practices that turn therapies into cash cows at the sick’s expense. If that goal is met, patients with rare diseases will still get new medicines – but hopefully at prices that don’t bankrupt families or public programs. And if prices become more rational, more patients can be treated, which in turn means more sales volume for industry at a fair price. Some Wall Street voices have noted that the industry might adapt by “making it up on volume” – i.e. a lower price but for a larger treated population, which is exactly how markets are supposed to work.

As reforms take shape, we’ll be watching to see if companies change their behavior. Will they continue pouring money into lobbying and loopholes, or start competing on value and broadening access? The rare disease community has hope that a new balance can be struck: one where innovation thrives and medicines are affordable. The ORPHAN Cures Act debate has made one thing clear: the era of unchecked orphan drug profiteering is coming to an end, and those who adapt by focusing on genuine medical value will thrive in the long run, while those clinging to the old ways may find the market – and public sentiment – turning against them.